[Skip to Navigation]
Sign In

Featured Clinical Reviews

Viewpoint
October 20, 2021

Administrative Expenses in the US Health Care System: Why So High?

Author Affiliations
  • 1Department of Health Care Policy, Harvard Medical School, Boston, Massachusetts
JAMA. 2021;326(17):1679-1680. doi:10.1001/jama.2021.17318

A variety of studies over the last 2 decades have found that administrative expenses account for approximately 15% to 25% of total national health care expenditures, an amount that represents an estimated $600 billion to $1 trillion per year of the total national health expenditures of $3.8 trillion in 2019.1 Billing and coding costs, physician administrative activities, and insurance administrative costs are the primary drivers of these expenses.2,3 In a new study, Sahni et al4 estimated that administrative spending was $950 billion in 2019, of which 94% was in 5 functional focus areas: financial transactions ecosystem, industry-agnostic corporate functions, industry-specific operational functions, customer and patient services, and administrative clinical support functions.

Even though administrative costs are often portrayed as inherently wasteful, some administrative activities, such as patient scheduling or staff hiring, would be required to manage any system. As a result, much of the contemporary administrative expense literature focuses on comparisons with comparatively more frugal nations, as well as analysis of “wasteful” administrative expenses. It seems clear by these comparisons that US health care–related administrative expenses are high.5 Moreover, administrative costs in the US health care system may be underestimated because estimates are typically focused on hospital and insurer costs. Whole segments of the health care sector (eg, employee benefit consultants or employer human resources costs) may be omitted from some estimates because they are often paid for by the employer and do not appear on hospital or insurer financial statements.

High administrative costs in the US reflect some unique aspects of the US health care system and those aspects reflect more specific societal values. For example, in part, high administrative costs stem from the value individuals in the US place on choice.1 A desire for choice gives rise to fragmentation of payers, which in turn generates complexity in billing and expenses related to plan choice (such as marketing costs). Some of these costs might be lowered with standardization of key administrative functions (such as standardized claims forms) or improved information technology capabilities (interoperability of medical records is of high importance), but other costs, such as marketing, are inherent when there is choice among plans.6

A broader way of thinking about high administrative costs in the US health care system is that they reflect the way in which the system deals with the inherent problems with health care markets. Specifically, because health care expenditures are uncertain, individuals need insurance. Without any countervailing force, insurance distorts market outcomes, causing utilization and prices to increase.

The US health system relies heavily on market-based solutions to address these issues. For example, in the commercial sector, there is reliance on competing insurers to manage utilization and negotiate with competing health care organizations for the best price.

Efforts to control utilization give rise to utilization management activities (such as prior authorization) or benefit designs that charge patients out of pocket when they seek care. Because competing insurers have different benefit designs, health care organizations and clinician practices must invest in activities to accommodate the out-of-pocket provisions of the different insurers and to collect patient fees. Additionally, efforts to control utilization through alternative payment models often require risk-adjustment systems, which create more administrative costs. Because there are multiple insurers seeking competitive advantage, these activities are difficult to standardize.

Similarly, efforts to control prices create administrative costs. These are in part related to negotiation, and those costs expand as the effects of the negotiations ripple through the system. For example, in efforts to negotiate better prices, insurers must be able to “threaten” to (and often do) exclude some clinicians or health care centers from their network. As a result, administrative dollars are spent to help find in-network clinicians or health care centers or steer patients to the lower-priced clinicians or health care centers in the network. Several industries have emerged to manage network and benefit complexity (eg, firms that support patients as they navigate their network and their benefit design, as well as firms that support employers in designing benefits and choosing insurers). The associated administrative costs are spread across payers, clinicians and health care centers, employers, and even patients.

The prescription drug market provides a microcosm of the issue. Patents for new drugs are granted to allow innovative firms to charge high prices and thus encourage innovation. However, when patents are combined with insurance, the resulting prices can be exorbitant. Insurers, in an effort to counteract the market power of manufacturers, develop institutions to offset some of the manufacturer market power. These institutions (eg, pharmacy benefit managers, which have market power to possibly command high fees) generate administrative costs related to formulary development, utilization management, and the bewildering system of rebates and related efforts to avoid plan cost-sharing provisions.

Overall, these market-driven activities may be worthwhile (the reductions in spending may justify the administrative expense), but nevertheless, they generate administrative costs. Other countries handle these activities in a more centralized way, standardizing or otherwise regulating dimensions of competition such as prices, benefit designs, or both. As a result, the administrative costs are reduced.

It is tempting to conclude that the US health system should move away from a market-based system to reduce administrative costs. Yet, it is important to acknowledge that government-run systems (and government intervention in market systems) may generate their own administrative costs associated with myriad regulations that govern health care organizations and markets. Moreover, while on balance government-run programs are generally administratively less costly, they have other drawbacks. Most important, government systems may prevent some individuals from obtaining the coverage or receiving the care they desire. The programs may limit choice and fail to incent efficiency or patient-centeredness. Government-managed cost containment (eg, price setting) runs the risk of adversely affecting access or quality of care. The extent to which those problems arise, and level of concern over whether some people are constrained in their behavior, depends on the perception of how well the government system (and the politics that will inevitably govern it) will function. Nonetheless, there may be some value in coordinated cost containment (eg, standardized plan designs or forms of payment).

Thus, efforts to control administrative costs must weigh savings with what may be lost. The challenge is finding the appropriate balance between market mechanisms and government intervention. At a minimum, policy needs to pay more attention to the administrative cost ramifications of different actions. Doing so will likely lead to more standardization and government involvement than currently exists in some aspects of health care. This is particularly important for areas that are more easily standardized, such as claims submissions and reporting requirements. It may also lead to simplifying, standardizing, scaling back, or redesigning existing initiatives, such as quality measurement, risk adjustments, payment models, and prior authorization rules. Overall, attempts to address administrative costs in a sustainable and permanent way will require careful consideration of how the US health system is designed, how much is standardized, and how the system balances the use of market mechanisms with the costs they sometimes entail.

Back to top
Article Information

Corresponding Author: Michael Chernew, PhD, Department of Health Care Policy, Harvard Medical School, 180 Longwood Ave, Boston, MA 02155 (chernew@hcp.med.harvard.edu).

Published Online: October 20, 2021. doi:10.1001/jama.2021.17318

Conflict of Interest Disclosures: Dr Chernew reported receiving research grants from Arnold Ventures, Blue Cross Blue Shield Association, Health Care Service Corporation, National Institute on Aging, Ballad Health, Commonwealth Fund, Signify Health LLC, Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, and National Institutes of Health; receiving personal fees from MJH Life Sciences (American Journal of Public Health), Elsevier, MITRE, American Economic Review, Commonwealth Fund, IDC Herzliya, Madalena Consulting, Chilmark Research, American College of Cardiology, Health(at)Scale, Blue Cross Blue Shield of Florida, Medaxiom, Humana, American Medical Association, America’s Health Insurance Plans, HealthEdge, RTI Health Solutions, Emory University, Washington University, and University of Pennsylvania; having equity in V-BID Health (partner), Virta Health, Archway Health, Curio Wellness (board of directors), and Health(at)Scale; serving (or having served) on advisory boards for the Congressional Budget Office (panel of health advisors), National Institute for Health Care Management, National Academies, AcademyHealth, National Quality Forum, Blue Cross Blue Shield Association, and Blue Health Intelligence; being a board member for the Health Care Cost Institute and the Massachusetts Health Connector (vice chair); and serving as the current chair of the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission. No other disclosures were reported.

References
1.
Tollen  L, Keating  E, Weil  A. How administrative spending contributes to excess US health spending. Health Affairs blog. Published online February 2020. Accessed August 30, 2021. https://www.healthaffairs.org/do/10.1377/hblog20200218.375060/full/
2.
Yong  PL, Saunders  RS, Olsen  L, eds.  The Healthcare Imperative: Lowering Costs and Improving Outcomes: Workshop Series Summary. National Academies Press; 2010.
3.
Shrank  WH, Rogstad  TL, Parekh  N.  Waste in the US health care system: estimated costs and potential for savings.   JAMA. 2019;322(15):1501-1509. doi:10.1001/jama.2019.13978PubMedGoogle ScholarCrossref
4.
Sahni  NR, Mishra  P, Carrus  B, Cutler  DM. Administrative Simplification: How to Save a Quarter-Trillion Dollars in US Healthcare. McKinsey & Company. Published October 20, 2021. https://www.mckinsey.com/industries/healthcare-systems-and-services/our-insights/administrative-simplification-how-to-save-a-quarter-trillion-dollars-in-US-healthcare
5.
Papanicolas  I, Woskie  LR, Jha  AK.  Health care spending in the United States and other high-income countries.   JAMA. 2018;319(10):1024-1039. doi:10.1001/jama.2018.1150PubMedGoogle ScholarCrossref
6.
Cutler  DM. Reducing administrative costs in US health care. Published March 2020. Accessed August 30, 2021. https://www.hamiltonproject.org/assets/files/Cutler_PP_LO.pdf
4 Comments for this article
EXPAND ALL
Administrative Costs in Primary Care
Joseph De Kay, D.O. | Maine Medical Center
I continue to find articles about the importance of limiting administrative costs and primary care interesting, but very slow to help. Having been in rural primary care since 1981, the required short essays on why a patient needs a cheap generic medication requested by a home health nurse, or needing to fill out a variety of forms to make clear a patient's type 1 diabetes has not suddenly gone in to remission six months since the last same forms were required, make this kind of work more difficult than it has to be. Today my coder needed help getting stool guaiac cards covered until we added diagnoses implicit in the original coding referring to upper GI hemorrhage and anemia, but not on the lists of accepted codes.

Attracting replacement clinicians for the low reimbursements and high hassle factor is more than challenging.

This same sort of discussion has been ongoing my entire life in practice. Here is hoping our younger colleagues can make the changes needed.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST: None Reported
READ MORE
Efficiency Makes Administrative Costs Disappear
Robert Burney, MD | Retired Anesthesiologist, formerly managed Ambulatory Surgery Centers
We were in price competition with other ambulatory surgery centers but were at or below anyone's cost in the state for anything we did. We set our costs at the bottom but still made money which was returned to investors. Many investors were surgeons, so they were happy to discuss ways of saving time or money. We standardized instruments and supplies for common procedures so no time was lost with preference cards. We did not allow outside records to be included in our charts (they were frequently wrong) so we did not invest in interoperable records. We looked at patient time spent in various areas and pulled charts monthly on outliers to look for improvement opportunities. I remarked once that laundry was one of the larger checks I wrote. The next month it was about half. I could see some but not all of the changes employees made to do this. An ophthalmologist wanted two OR's to do his cases more quickly. After a month, he decided he couldn't keep up with our staff and one OR would be fine. Suggestions were encouraged from everyone. It worked.
CONFLICT OF INTEREST: None Reported
READ MORE
"It is tempting to conclude..."
Kenneth Dolkart, MD FACP | Geisel School of Medicine
Drs Chernew and Mintz state that “it is tempting to conclude that the US health system should move away from a market-based system to reduce administrative costs" and that "while on balance government-run programs are administratively less costly they may prevent some individuals from obtaining the coverage…they desire." Really? As a geriatrician and internist 38 years in practice, it is not patients covered by low overhead traditional Medicare who are complaining about their costs or “choice” nor starting GoFundMe pages to pay for their uncovered essential care. It is not those covered by the government insurance fund of Medicare, but the younger, less ill population covered by market-driven Employer-Sponsored Insurance who have observed exponential rises in profit-driven administrative costs, premiums, deductibles and coinsurance. “Limited choice” or “failure to invent patient-centerness” are truly non issues for the 30 million Americans allowed to have no health insurance at all. As physicians, we can do better than allow a failed market system to offer gaping holes of coverage for younger Americans whose “choice” is to either avoid medical care altogether or endure bankruptcy.
CONFLICT OF INTEREST: Member, Physicians for a National Health Program, but writing as an individual
READ MORE
Missing the Forest
Mark Brakke, MD | Family Practice MD, retired
US health care costs are 50 to 100 % higher than those in virtually all other modern nations.

US life expectancy, and maternal and infant mortality are worse than other modern nations. US patients are less satisfied than those in other nations. The advent of managed care (HMO) models and the merging of hospitals and insurance companies is correlated with US health care costs rising much faster than those in other nations.

There is only one realistic fix. We need single payer health care. Improved Medicare for all.

Imagine that US healthcare costs
were only 20% higher than other modern nations. Do some math. Calculate the economic loss over a lifespan of 75 years using a conservative rate of return on the dollars that could be available for something other than healthcare (an accountant would say this is an "opportunity cost" calculation). You will be astounded at the $ figure.

If we are serious about pursuing equity in the US we need to fix the healthcare mess.

CONFLICT OF INTEREST: None Reported
READ MORE
×